当前位置:主页 > 论文百科 > 研究生论文 >

留学生assignment代写:亚当·斯密及共同农业政策

发布时间:2016-08-13 06:59

亚当·斯密及共同农业政策
The Common Agriculture Policy And Adam Smith 

在经济日趋全球化之后,一个有大型贸易集团共同市场的出现,世界各国的竞争已经被迫变为经济一体。在数百年的消费理论选,这几乎肯定会导致一个必然更低的价格和更有效的生产所有产品的结论。然而,正如许多国家的情况一样,,欧洲联盟(欧盟)已经成功地通过使用一个共同的农业政策创造一个人工市场的农产品。分析的重点勾勒出欧盟共同农业政策的框架,严格分析它所产生的福利的负面影响,并通过检查一个国家的(英国)的斗争与共同的农业政策表现出这样的影响。在政府干预的问题上,政府干预的争议也一直是一个重大问题。应欧盟的政府干预农业市场来帮助它自己的经济,和亚当·斯密会怎么想呢?

In the wake of an increasingly globalized economy, one that has seen the emergence of large trade blocs and common markets, the nations of the world have been competitively forced into becoming more economically integrated year after year. In light of hundreds of years of consumer theory, this would almost certainly lead one to a conclusion of necessarily lower prices and more efficient production on almost all products. However, as is the case in many nations, the European Union (EU) has succeeded in creating an artificial market for agricultural products through the use of a Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). It is the focus of this analysis to outline the framework of the Common Agricultural Policy of the European Union, analyze strictly the negative effects it creates on welfare, and exhibit such effects through the examination of one nation's (United Kingdom) struggle with the Common Agricultural Policy. In light of the CAP, the controversy of government intervention has also have been a major issue. Should the governments of the EU interfere with the agricultural market to help it's own economy, and what would Adam Smith think of this? With disregard for the invisible hand, the EU is directing the economy and the people.

The Common Agricultural Policy is a policy, set forth by the European Union (EU), which is comprised of a set of rules that regulate the production, trade, and processing of agricultural products. The CAP currently accounts for almost fifty percent of the EU budget, however, this number continues to decrease over the years. The CAP is significant in that it symbolizes Europe's switch from sovereignty on a national level to a European level.

The Treaty of Rome, in July 1958, formed the foundation for a unified Europe via the implementation of the general objectives for the CAP. "The CAP was established as a means of rectifying the deficit in food production within Europe through supporting internal prices and incomes" (Blair 123-124). The CAP succeeded in realizing it's initial goals of increased production and productivity, stabilized markets, secured supplies, and farmer protection. However, the system included problems, which became apparent as the Community established a surplus for most of its agricultural products. First, the CAP increased output beyond the market's need via the guaranteeing of prices through intervention and production aids. Second, the very success of the Cap caused tension within the Community's trading partners as subsidized exports affected the market, and thirdly, the desire to produce more food brought with it environmental damage to certain regions (Blair 123-4).

The legal basis for the CAP is defined in Articles 32-38 in Title II of the EC Treaty, in which, Articles 33-34 form the basic foundation for the CAP. Article 33 lists the objectives of the CAP as a means, "to increase agricultural productivity by promoting technical progress and by ensuring the rational development of agricultural production and the optimum utilization of the factors of production, to ensure a fair standard of living for the agricultural community, in particular by increasing the individual earnings of persons engaged in agriculture, to stabilize markets, to assure the availability of supplies, and to ensure that supplies reach consumers at reasonable prices" (europa.eu.int).

Through Article 34 came the creation of the Common Organization of the Agricultural Markets (COM). These COM's were to take on one of three different forms, depending on the product. They successfully eliminate obstacles to intra-Union trade while also keeping a common customs barrier with respect to countries outside the Union. Results of the COM's include a unified market in which products move freely between nations, community preference, in which EU products are always given preference, price advantage over imported products, and financial solidarity in which all expenses by the CAP are covered by the Community budget.

The CAP is largely funded by the European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund (EAGGF), which accounts for a substantial part of the Community budget. This fund is divided into two distinct sections, the Guidance section and the Guarantee section. The Guidance section is one of the structural funds, which contributes to the structural reforms in agriculture and the development of rural areas; the Guarantee section, the more integral section, funds expenditures concerning the common organization of the markets. Further financing of the CAP comes from storage levies, manufacture levies, and portions of each member state's GNP.

The CAP has had a long history of reform, and is nowhere near perfect. The first attempt at reform came just ten years after its implementation. In 1968, the Mansholt Plan was put into effect in an attempt to reduce the number of people in the agriculture business and to promote more efficient means of agricultural production. In 1972, the extensive food surpluses were targeted through the creation of structural measures designed to modernize European agriculture. This attempt at reform is generally regarded as a failure because many of the problems it tried to fix were still left unchecked. In 1983, a publication was released entitled, The Green Paper, which sought to balance the ongoing disparities between supply and demand through improvements in production. In 1988, the European Council agreed on various reform measures. The most important was the "agricultural expenditure guideline," which limited the percentage of CAP expenditure in the overall budget. In 1991-92!,the future of the CAP was addressed through what has been called, "the MacSharry Reforms." The key aspects of the reforms included the cutback of agricultural prices to make the products more competitive, compensation for farmers that incurred a loss in income, and environmental protection. "The reform of 1992 was generally regarded as successful, with positive effects on European agriculture. However, international trends, the enlargement towards Central and Eastern Europe, the preparation of the single currency causing budget constraints, the increasing competitiveness of products from non-member countries, and a new round of World Trade Organization negotiations forced further adaptation of the CAP" (europa.eu.int). In July 1997, "Agenda 2000" was created to address many of the important issues facing the EU and the CAP. The key focuses of this new agenda are the reinforcement of the competitiveness of agricultural commodities in domestic and world markets, the promotion of a fair standard of living, the creation of extra sources of income for farmers, a new rural development policy, revamped environmental considerations, better food quality and safety, and the simplification of CAP legislation.

The European Union's common agricultural policy protects and subsidizes agriculture so heavily as to bring serious social losses to the Economic Union. The policy creates inefficiencies in the agriculture sector as well as other sectors of society such as manufacturing, textiles, and service industries. Furthermore, "there have been many economic consequences of the CAP, including the high level of protection, the burdens on consumers, taxpayers, and the EU budget, environmental damage, the harm to international trading relations, and the failure to raise farmers' incomes" (Howarth 4).

The question at hand is how the policy, which is seen as an economic benefit for the European Union's agriculture sector, is, in reality, stymieing growth and the efficient allocation of resources. There have been a number of negative effects on the European Union countries. First and foremost, the Common Agricultural Policy has kept agricultural prices in the member countries above world market prices. "The CAP has encouraged production of certain products to the extent that net importers of these products have become net exporters" (Rosenblatt 9). Also, the CAP has contributed to large agricultural net export or stock-building by the European community. This has contributed to the CAP hindering the economies of the EU member countries. Higher food prices, which the CAP causes, and which fall hardest on the least well off, hinder economic development and reduce international competitiveness and EU employment. Consumers lose twice under this policy since they have to pay higher prices for their good and pay taxes to subsidize the agricultural sector.

The CAP has also led to inefficiencies in production and the European Union's total budget. The European Union's expenditures on agriculture consume roughly 45 percent of their total budget (Rosenblatt 36). The expenditures are paid to keep farmers from letting land go idle, and there is no stipulation on what types of crops are to be grown on this land. Under the Common Agricultural Policy, farmers tend to harvest more profitable crops on land that is not as suitable for their growth. For example, producers have switched over from producing wheat and oil seeds to butter because the EU has such a high price support for it. This causes the market to go from excess supply to excess demand, and the producers are becoming a net exporter of butter (Pugel 312). Thus, farmers may actually grow crops for which production costs are not covered by the prevailing market prices, but payments make production of these crops profitable to them.

The CAP has also caused concern for the environment as well as concerns for the economy. Because of the subsidies provided to farmers, they have the incentive to produce more agricultural products because they will receive more money. The CAP price policies have encouraged intensive farming and the overuse of antibiotics, pesticides, and nitrates. This has put a strain on the environment and has concerned the people of the European Union. The policy did not foresee farmers overproducing and over using chemicals, but this has become an indirect cost created by the policy. Europeans are also concerned with food safety because of farmers using so many chemicals in production. Farmers have been getting away with using the chemicals and unsafe practices because of the limited food safety regulations. Policymakers believed that high price supports would lead to higher food safety and quality. "High support prices do not increase either food safety or quality: indeed, minimum prices and intervention guarantees encourage low quality and standardized produce" (Consumers in Europe group).

Under the CAP, the European Union countries have shifted from net importers to net exporters of food products. With the EU subsidizing the agricultural sector so heavily, as to raise some sectors, such as non-grain crops, to eight times larger than it would normally be at (Borrell 18). This has drawn resources and labor out of other sectors of the economy and into the agricultural sector because of the subsidies. "These costs and resource misallocation reduce the total output and income of the European Union" (Borrell 18). Borrell charts the percentage changes in specific industries due to the CAP in the EU. For example, the CAP has caused negative changes in the following industries: construction and utilities are down one percent, the service industry is down two percent, the manufacturing sector in down almost five percent, and other primary products are down almost six percent (Borrell 20). This information demonstrates that CAP is taking away resources from these service type industries and placing it in the agricultural sector. The transference of these resources is coming at the cost of the consumers, taxpayers, or society as a whole.

The effects of the EU Common Agricultural Policy have not just altered the European Union's economy, but it has also restructured other economies throughout the world. The CAP has caused farmers to produce a surplus of agricultural goods in the EU. This has led to dumping of these products into other countries. As a result, importing countries have shifted away from producing agricultural goods to goods such as manufacturing, construction, services, and other primary goods. The United States and Canada have experienced a decrease in agricultural production due to the CAP. Combined, the United States and Canada have experienced a decrease of approximately 8.1 percent across primary agricultural goods (as much as 13 percent for non-grain products to as low as 2.9 percent for meat products) (Borrell 23). Also, with cropping exports down between 26 and 45 percent, this shows implications that output has been dropping in the cropping sector. The effects of the CAP have also shifted resources in Australia and New Zealand from agriculture to other primary industries. These countries have experienced an expansion in the mining and forestry industries of 7.5 percent (Borrell 21). These examples display how the CAP has suppressed exports of agricultural products and has led to the allocation of resources into other industries in other countries.

It is apparent that the Common Agricultural Policy has been and is causing problems not only in the European Union, but it has also been creating problems in the rest of the world. What the CAP has effectively done to the European Union is that it has caused it to become a net exporter of agricultural products when it should be a net importer of these goods. The EU's policy has changed the world markets for agricultural goods and has imposed significant costs to the EU's consumers and taxpayers. Consumers and taxpayers in the EU bear most of the cost of 70 to 80 million US dollars a year, which is used to increase farmers' incomes. The taxpayers and consumers are responsible for this increase in cost, which in turn causes an increase in unemployment. "...The CAP was responsible for a loss of one million jobs in the EU manufacturing sector alone. The EU unemployment rate is currently around 10 percent, which is currently 40 percent higher than the OECD (Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development) average" (Borrell 20). It is clear that the Common Agricultural Policy is responsible for increases in unemployment, increases in taxpayer cost and consumer burden, drops in farmer income, and harm to international relations. If the CAP were not implemented, many of these issues would be alleviated.

There have been significant losses to the European Union as a whole because of the CAP. To understand, however, what this does to an individual country, an analysis of Britain experience must be looked at. In 1973, Great Britain entered the European Community and, therefore, accepted the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). The acceptance of the CAP caused Britain to move from an agricultural market of free trade and cheap food, to an agricultural market that became the pawn of the European Union's protectionism (Harvey 2). The CAP's main goal was, "to keep agricultural market's stable, ensure that farmers earn a fair living, and provide consumers with affordable food supplies" (Thinkquest Library 2). The CAP achieved many goals it set out to accomplish. The very generous price supports to farmers and technological innovation have caused surpluses that are not being offset by a decreasing demand.

The CAP has run into criticism in recent times by both British consumers and taxpayers alike, and many citizens and even farmers are calling for its reform. One recent event that caused the European Union to rethink the restrictions of the CAP was the outbreak of mad cow disease in Britain. British cattle that were infected by mad cow disease experienced nervous system breakdown and eventually death. The beef industry suffered in Britain and many of the cattle had to be put to death because they were not suitable to eat. Therefore, the European Union, in 1996, had to impose a British beef export ban (Barclay 21). The ban, and the fall in beef consumption in the UK market, caused the United Kingdom cattle market to lose sales totaling 800 million pounds (Barclay 22). The British were not allowed to export tainted beef to member countries and many member countries feared to import any British beef (Barclay 22).

The CAP has hurt Britain in more ways than one. British consumers have been burdened by higher domestic agriculture prices because of CAP policies when they could easily go buy the same product cheaper in the world market. The taxpayers in Britain have been burdened by taxes the European Union imposes to finance subsidies to farmers. Admittedly, the United Kingdom would still have to face the mad cow dilemma regardless of its prior entry in the Union. However, the British would be able to develop a unilateral policy in which they would be free from the strict requirements of the European Union.

The abolishment of the Common Agricultural Policy within the European Union would raise the welfare of a higher percentage of citizenry than that which its embracement does. The European Union, as many international factors may, feels a strong propensity to maintain what appears to be a formidable agriculture industry in the name of such principles as continental pride, national security, and political agendas. However, in the long run, such blatant supports to an industry should be ample evidence of its failure to survive at the government demanded level, and should implore policymakers and citizens alike to simply remove the handcuff from the invisible hand.

The analysis of the Common Agricultural Policy has lead to insights on what Adam Smith might think of this situation. The best approach to Smith and his views on the CAP can be found in his book, the Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations: Book IV: On Systems of Political Economy, Chapter II: On Restraints upon the Importation from Foreign Countries of such Goods as can be produced at Home. In Smith's Wealth of Nations, he states, "Taxes imposed with a view to prevent, or even to diminish importation, are evidently as destructive of the revenue of the customs as of the freedom of trade" (Smith Book IV, Chapter 2). For a government to involve itself in disrupting the freedom of trade through taxes it has not only ruined trade but it has lost relations with other countries. Smith would look at the EU and see that there have been no significant gains made by the CAP. The CAP in essence is creating a monopoly in Europe on agricultural products. Foreign produced goods are taxed so heavily that EU farmers can enjoy production with little competition.

First, "the general industry of the society never can exceed what the capital of the society can employ" (Smith Book IV, Chapter 2). The EU only has so much land and capital that it can devote to agriculture and the CAP has seen a movement of both to this sector. The movement of capital and labor has led to inefficient production methods. Farmers are overproducing a product that the market in Europe cannot bear. Smith would point out the overproduction is not a benefit to the trade bloc and creates a loss. Other industries would benefit more from the capital and labor then agriculture does. From data that has been collected and could be readily available to Smith, he would point out that production of agriculture goods is becoming the dominating sector of the economy. But society can only employ a specific amount of labor and that society is unable to go beyond what capital it can maintain. Smith points this out in his book stating, "It (government regulation) can only divert a part of it (labor) into a direction into which it might not otherwise have gone: and it is by no means certain that this artificial direction is likely to be more advantageous to the society than that into which it would have gone of its own accord" (Smith Book IV, Chapter 2). The CAP has moved labor into an industry artificially and this labor would be more beneficial to society if it were in other sectors of the economy; manufacturing, textiles, or the service industry. The EU would see higher production in other industries if the capital and labor would not be diverted to agriculture.

Smith would see this policy as a monopoly and that the government is controlling private people in what direction to employ capital and labor. This type of policy is, to Smith, in just about every case useless or hurtful to economic flow of capital and labor. The CAP is doing exactly what Smith believes it would do, hurt the economy; since Europe cannot produce agricultural products cheaply, it subsidizes them and in turn deteriorates the economy. Smith quotes a great maxim in his book that fits perfectly for this situation, "It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family never to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy" (Smith Book IV, Chapter 2). Europe is producing goods that cost them more if they bought them abroad. Europe does not have a comparative advantage over other countries in all agricultural products and would find it to their advantage to purchase these products from countries.

The invisible hand theory of Smith's would be the foundation of his argument for the abolishment of the CAP. No government policy can replace the invisible hand to efficiently promote the economic good of the nation or nations. The individual will promote the public good better and more effectively than the government's policy in question. "By pursuing his won interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectively than when he rally intends to promote it" (Smith Book IV, Chapter 2). A government policy that is created to promote the public interest will do just the opposite, since the individual will not support it to its greatest value. The ones that know what is best for society is not the bureaucrat leader but the individual, since he clearly knows what is better for his own self interest.

The invisible hand theory would also be used to explain the lower food quality that has resulted from the CAP. With low government regulations on food quality, farmers do not have to worry about how they produce food but how much they can produce. The consumer would be better off without the CAP since competition would result in a more competitive environment in which European farmers would have to participate. The invisible hand would guide farmers to produce better quality of foods since it would be in their self interest if they wanted to sell more of their good. Without this competition, farmers do not worry about their own self-interest, and as a result, the interest of society has vanished. The government has successfully removed the public's self interest for food quality because there is no incentive for farmers to produce at the highest quality.

From the analysis of the CAP and Adam Smith, it is evident that the CAP has created serious social and economic welfare losses. It has eliminated the invisible hand and international competition. This has caused the EU to experience higher prices in agricultural products at the expense of consumers and other industries. This type of mercantilism does not benefit the economies of the EU or the rest of the world. If Adam Smith were still alive today he would be the first to denounce the Common Agricultural Policy and its harmful effects on the economy and consumer. Yet Smith, with a little bit of irony, would be a Commissioner of Customs while he ridiculed the policy. All in all, Smith, as well as economist today, would see the errors the EU has created as a system that exemplifies government intervention at its worst. The allocation of resources and guidance of the economy should be left to the people of the economy because the invisible hand will direct it better than a!




本文编号:92691

资料下载
论文发表

本文链接:https://www.wllwen.com/wenshubaike/lwfw/92691.html


Copyright(c)文论论文网All Rights Reserved | 网站地图 |

版权申明:资料由用户cf488***提供,本站仅收录摘要或目录,作者需要删除请E-mail邮箱bigeng88@qq.com